Recebido: 06-03-2023 | Aprovado: 03-04-2023
Ahmed Hrifa, National School Of Business and Management of Settat,
Morocco (ahmedhrifa00@gmail.com)
Como citar este artigo:
Hrifa, A. (2023). Análise da possibilidade de passar a uma nova etapa : no processo de flexibilização do regime cambial em Marrocos. [RMd] RevistaMultidisciplinar, 5(2), 79–103.
https://doi.org/10.23882/rmd.23131
Abstract: Given the profound structural changes in the national economy and its increasingly increased openness to the outside world, the transition to a more flexible exchange rate regime constitutes a fundamental reform in order to strengthen the competitiveness of the economy, its resilience to exogenous shocks and the level of its potential growth. However, the transition to more flexibility is not without risk, it would be accompanied by massive inflows of foreign capital motivated mainly by expectations of appreciation of the national currency and the interest rate differential, which will result in excess bank liquidity and excessive growth of reserves causing greater inflationary pressures and aggravation of financial fragilities and exchange rate risk. The objective of this article is therefore to question the capacity of the Moroccan economy through its macroeconomic fundamentals, its financial markets and its institutions, to support the transition to a new stage in the process of flexibilization of the exchange rate regime. The results show that this transition still has to wait, the ground needs to be further prepared.
Keywords: Exchange rate regime, exchange rate, flexibility, Morocco.
Since the collapse of the Bretton Woods fixed exchange rate system in the 1970s
and underpinned by a series of currency crises in several countries, the issue
of exchange rate stability has received particular attention . In this wake,
empirical work proves that it is not easy to maintain a system of long-term
fixity, especially in a context of liberalization of capital flows. Indeed,
fixity regimes have been considered unsustainable and crisis-generating (Esmak,
2016). To this end, the transition to a more flexible exchange rate regime has
become inevitable for some emerging and developing countries. For other
countries, the path to flexibility was much smoother and the transition to more
flexible regimes was mainly determined by the degree of economic and financial
openness.
In Morocco, the exchange rate regime put in place by the monetary authorities
has made it possible to maintain a framework of macro-economic stability.
However, our country has been engaged, since the beginning of the 1980s, in a
broad process of liberalization of its economy which has affected almost all
sectors (Sabar & Belhouari, 2018). Consequently, the Moroccan economy is
increasingly exposed to external shocks and requires, for this purpose, a
greater capacity for adjustment and absorption of shocks. Therefore, it is
important to choose the right exchange rate regime for the country's economy.
The objective of this article consists in questioning the capacity of the
Moroccan economy through its macroeconomic fundamentals, its financial markets
and its institutions, to support the passage to a new stage in the process of
flexibilization of the exchange rate regime, namely inflation targeting. To do
this, we first present the economic foundations of exchange rate regimes.
Secondly, we will trace the trajectory of the management of the exchange rate
regime in Morocco, correlated with the main macroeconomic effects. Thus, we are
interested in what follows to discuss the merits of the arguments that militated
for the adoption of the progressive regime of flexibility. It is fundamentally a
matter of questioning the expected effects of the very long-term floating of the
dirham in terms of adjustment, liquidity and confidence (credibility).
The examination of these factors will lead us to evaluate the role of the
exchange rate policy in the macroeconomic adjustment in Morocco as well as the
prospects for the choice of an optimal exchange rate policy. Finally, the last
axis of the article will be devoted to the experiences of the transition to
floating of certain economies and the main lessons to be learned in order to
cushion the negative impacts of the transition to a floating exchange rate
regime.
The exchange regime or
system designates the set of principles and rules organizing the framework which
determines the nominal value of the domestic currency. This value, called the
nominal exchange rate, can be fixed in relation to one or more foreign
currencies or in relation to a commodity such as gold or silver. Therefore, the
exchange rate regime governs the interventions of the monetary authorities in
the foreign exchange market and possibly the conduct of monetary policy in order
to defend or influence the evolution of the exchange rate (Camara, 2014).
Historically, the classification of exchange rate regimes
has been the subject of controversy. Placing such and such a regime in such and
such a category turns out to be today, even for specialized institutions such as
the IMF and the World Bank, one of the greatest challenges at the empirical
level. Since 1950, the IMF's annual report “Exchange Arrangements and Exchange
Restrictions” has consistently been the primary source of information on
nations' exchange rate regimes.
Indeed, there are at least two ways of classifying countries according to their
exchange rate regime. We have the so-called “de jure” classification, which was
introduced by the Bretton Woods SMI, and the “de facto” classification, which is
based on empirical analyzes.
The de jure classification is the IMF classification which asked the country to
proclaim the exchange rate regime they put in place as belonging to one of the
categories defined beforehand. Indeed, this classification grouped countries
into three categories of exchange rate regimes, namely:
-
Fixed exchange rate regimes;
-
Limited flexibility plans;
-
High flexibility plans.
This type of classification has the advantage of covering a wide range of
countries and can be automatically and frequently updated and provide a
consistent historical database. However, experience has shown that some
countries apply exchange rate regimes other than those they officially declare.
These are de facto exchange rate regimes, hence the de facto classification.
Since 1998, the IMF takes into account the degree of exchange rate variability
and the economic policies that affect the Nominal Exchange Rate (NER
).
There are various de facto classifications, because a de facto classification
depends on the criteria and methods retained by each author proposing a
classification. De facto classifications are obtained using either:
-
The statistical method, or,
-
The analytical method of economic policies, or
-
The method combining the first two.
According to the de facto classification of the IMF (2021), there are ten
categories of exchange rate regimes which are presented as follows:
Table 1: Classification of exchange rate arrangements by the IMF in 2021
Type |
Categories |
||||
Hard pegs |
Exchange arrangement with no separate legal tender |
Currency board arrangement |
- |
- |
|
Soft pegs |
Conventional pegged arrangement |
Pegged exchange rate within horizontal bands |
Stabilized arrangement |
Crawling peg |
Crawl-like arrangement |
Floating regimes |
Floating |
Free floating |
- |
- |
|
Residual |
Other managed arrangement |
- |
|
- |
|
Source: IMF, Annual
Report on Exchange Arrangements and Exchange Restrictions, 2021.
The choice of an exchange rate regime is a question of capital importance,
because it calls into question the economic policy of a country and determines
the methods of its insertion into the international fabric.
Table 2:
Exchange rate arrangements,
percent of IMF members in 2021
Exchange Rate Arrangement |
2021 |
Hard peg |
13% |
Soft peg |
47,6% |
Floating |
33,2% |
Residual |
6,2% |
Source: IMF, Annual Report on Exchange
Arrangements and Exchange Restrictions, 2021
Debates the question of choice of the optimal
exchange rate regime are old, but not yet exhausted (Alhadj
et al., 2019).
In short, two series of new facts have updated this question of the choice of
the optimal exchange rate regime, namely:
·
The adoption of unsustainable exchange rate
regimes has been widely seen as one of the causes of the recent succession of
exchange rate crises, including the European Exchange Rate Mechanism crisis of
1992, the Mexican Peso crisis of 1994-1995, and the Asian crisis of 1997 (Esaka,
2010) and preventing financial crises in general has become one of the
priorities of political decision-makers in many countries (Nakatani, R., 2018).
·
The effects of the exchange rate regime on the
economy. Even if most of the work carried out so far has focused on the impacts
of exchange rate regime choices on the variability of output and inflation (Alhadj
et al., 2019).
Over time, the issue of choice of exchange rate
regime has been examined from different theoretical angles. The emergence of new
theoretical viewpoints has been influenced by developments and crises in the
international monetary system. In what follows, the theories are discussed in
chronological order, with the exception of political and institutional factors.
The chronological order of the theories makes it easier to understand new
developments; this does not mean that the first theories have been forgotten.
The optimal currency area theory and the Mundell-Fleming model remain key
elements of macroeconomic theory in the open economy today. However, before
going on to examine the various determinants of the choice of the exchange rate
regime, the advantages and disadvantages of the various exchange rate regimes
will be examined first.
The choice of exchange rate regime depends on
the economic environment and the economic policy objectives of the country, a
major change that has affected economic policy and, in particular, exchange rate
policy in recent decades has been the liberalization of movements of capital.
International capital movements have made it possible to maintain a fixed
exchange rate even if a country has a current account deficit. On the other
hand, the free movement of capital can also make it more difficult to pursue the
desired monetary policy and maintain a fixed exchange rate (Sylviane, 2019).
Hefnaoui and Iaataren (2022) concluded that all
exchange rate regimes are feasible when fundamentals are good. The problems only
show up in the behavior of the exchange rate; they are not caused by the
exchange rate regime. But such a conclusion would be too extreme. The experience
that began with the collapse of the Bretton Woods system and was followed by
many other episodes, including the East Asian crises. The problem lies in the
combination of tight control of fixed rates with monetary independence and high
capital mobility. This does not mean that extremes, pure floating and rigidly
fixed diets are the only options.
Jouamaa and Rhiati (2021) found that the
exchange rate is one of the most influential variables in a given economy,
because any fluctuation in exchange rates can affect the stock of external debt
, the competitiveness of import and export companies, and the income and
transfers from tourism of Moroccan nationals abroad. The crucial role of the
exchange rate is therefore further strengthened within the framework of the
system of managed flexibility and the continuation of the liberalization
process. This notion of exchange rate loses its meaning in the event of
persistent differences in inflation rates between the country in question and
its trading partner.
EL Yamani et al., (2021) analyzed the
relationship between the exchange rate and economic growth in Morocco. They
found that considering the exchange rate as a facilitating condition for growth
is important, but this does not mean that the exchange rate policy can replace
the presence of efficient, disciplined and creative human capital; at a
sustained level of investment; a favorable climate for foreign investment; to
developed financial markets; a sound monetary policy framework; to a high level
of institutional quality and to a competitive and technologically sophisticated
exportable offer.
2.
Methodology
The notion of methodology, as a set of rules and
approaches adopted to conduct research, so important in the history of the
structuring of scientific disciplines, is crucial (De Mourat et al., 2015).
In this article, we have adopted two research
methods, namely: documentary research and comparative research.
Documentary research consists of collecting
information in relation to one's research subject from reliable sources.
Depending on his subject, the investigator selects the most relevant documents,
likely to provide him with essential information for the advancement of his
research.
However, the comparative research can be defined
as a decision support tool which is based on the work of collecting, analyzing
and comparing information with a given purpose.
From the introduction of Islam in Morocco, the
monetary question was one of the major state bases, in fact, the Arab-Muslim
civilization has adapted two main currencies since its entry into Morocco. It
was either a
[1]gold-silver
bimetallism, dinar in gold and dirham in silver and Okaya in bronze. The
exchange between the Moroccan and foreign currency was not regulated by any
text, it was the business of traders and money changers installed in the cities
and the enclosures of the ports. The banking network was practically
non-existent: only a few foreign banks had branches in Morocco, like the
national discount counter in Paris, which had three branches in Tangier,
Casablanca and Essaouira. Exchange rates could also vary from city to city and
the lack of means of communication accentuated these disparities. All these
conditions and many others led to the creation of the state bank in Morocco with
the intervention of several foreign powers (Mezen & Echkoundi, 2020). Then, from
1912, date of the beginning of the French protectorate on Moroccan territory,
the Moroccan franc was the main monetary unit of the Kingdom. The latter
circulated until October 17, 1957, date of the creation of the Moroccan dirham
which remained attached to the French Franc (FF
) by a fixed parity, of which: 1 Dh = 100
centimes = 100 old Moroccan francs and fixing its parity at 175 .61 mg gold (El
Yamani et al., 2018). From May 1973, the link with the French franc was broken,
the monetary authorities chose to adopt an administered regime with the
objective of managing the stability of the effective parity vis-à-vis a basket
of currencies (Esmak, 2016).
Table 3: The Moroccan DH peg weights in the 1973 and 1980 baskets
Currencies |
FF |
US $ |
ESP |
LI |
£ |
DM |
FS |
FB |
FH |
1973 |
38% |
15% |
15% |
8% |
8% |
7% |
4% |
3% |
2% |
1980 |
25% |
32% |
15% |
5% |
8% |
7% |
2% |
4% |
2% |
Source: Bank Al-Maghrib
The three-year plan
(1970-1980) was unable to achieve its objectives because of the structural
nature of the imbalances, which could not be corrected by timid temporary
measures; until 1980 the exchange rate was not used as an instrument of trade
protection. BAM refused to use it as a means of regulating trade policy, giving
priority to the stability of the dirham. Indeed, the stabilization policy
implemented by the monetary authorities was followed by a restrictive policy
with the aim of fighting against inflation, through the control of the creation
of Moroccan cash and based on policies of credit supervision and selectivity.
However, after this period, the monetary authorities accepted the principle of a
long-term impact of the exchange rate on the structure of foreign trade, making
the exchange rate policy active. In reaction to the above, since 1983, the
adoption of a SAP
marked the beginning of a
series of reforms undertaken by the public authorities to modernize and
liberalize the economy in order to meet the requirements of the new environment
international economy, by implementing a policy of gradual and continuous
economic and financial liberalization, the aim of which is to remedy external
imbalances. In May 1990, in view of the association agreement between Morocco
and the European Union and greater integration of the Moroccan economy in this
area, the dirham was devalued by 9.25 %. Notwithstanding, the exchange rate
policy aimed at a significant real depreciation was insufficient. Once again,
the devaluation policy did not really have the expected positive effects. The
expected result was not up to the means used. In fact, the devaluation of the
dirham did little to contain the expansion of imports in particular. The limit
of the exchange rate policy, the structural difficulties of the Moroccan economy
and the rise in the import prices of raw materials entering into the
intermediate consumption of exported products penalized Moroccan exports and
pushed the country to undertake a reform comprehensive strategy centered on the
liberalization of the economy which was also accompanied by an overhaul of the
monetary and exchange rate policy. Moreover, The 90s saw an accentuation of the
liberalization movement. In January 1993, a process of liberalization of the
current account and the capital account began, which culminated in June 1996 in
a passage towards a regime with a fluctuation band around a central parity in
relation to a basket of currencies. In 1999, with the creation of the euro, the
monetary authorities rearranged the basket by replacing the old European
currencies with the euro. This exchange rate policy did not exempt the Moroccan
dirham from revaluation, following the depreciation of the dollar since 2001 and
because of the latter's high weight in the reference basket. Such a policy has
affected part of the competitiveness of its exports due to the appreciation of
the dirham against the currencies of its direct competitors, in particular
Tunisia and Egypt, pushing BAM to rearrange the basket by limiting its
composition to Euro and US Dollar (respective weightings of 80% and 20%). This
change resulted in a devaluation of about 5% of the national currency. Morocco's
exchange rate regime has always had the mission of ensuring a certain stability
of the dirham in relation to its main partners, with the aim of maintaining a
balanced balance of payments. The real exchange rate of the dirham has been on a
slow but steady downward trend since the early 2000s (Henri-Louis, 2019). The
phase from 2007 to 2010 constitutes the first reflections on the reform project
of the exchange rate regime, well before Morocco obtained the agreement for the
Liquidity Precautionary Line (LPL
) and at the same time to
accompany the project Casablanca Finance City (CFC
) and the free trade
agreements signed with several countries. Morocco as opposed to Egypt and Turkey
wants a gradual and orderly transition to a flexible regime under the assistance
of several international bodies such as central banks, the International
Monetary Fund & the World Bank to multiply the chances of success. From 2010 to
2015, Morocco moved to the phase of analysis, benchmarking and preparation for
reform. On April 15, 2015, the monetary authorities had decided to update the
currency weightings of the dirham quotation basket, but in favor of the American
dollar, to become 60% for the Euro and 40% for the American Dollar, in order to
reflect, at best the structure of foreign trade. This last update of the trading
basket should constitute a first step in the process of transition towards a
more flexible exchange rate regime aimed at supporting the capacity of the
Moroccan economy to attract more direct investment from the European Union.
Between 2008 and 2016, the euro-dirham exchange rates evolved almost
symmetrically with the dollar-dirham exchange rates. Then, it was from 2016 that
Morocco began preparing all stakeholders. The objective is to acquire the human,
organizational and efficient information system resources necessary for the
accomplishment of this reform project. The first interested party is BAM
(forecasting model, etc.). Preparation assistance also goes to economic
operators, public and private, especially in terms of hedging against exchange
rate risk. Awareness and assistance aims to prepare the banking system for this
change. It remains undeniable that the exchange rate regime applied up to this
stage has contributed to ensuring a certain stability of the national economy,
the fact remains that the effects of the international financial crisis have
highlighted certain limitations of this diet. Indeed, the current account
deficit widened gradually to reach -9.5% of GDP in 2012 and the level of foreign
exchange reserves returned to the equivalent of 4 months of imports of goods and
services
[2]at the level of
the same year. These developments militate in favor of the transition towards
greater flexibility of the exchange rate regime, in particular in the current
context marked by the gradual improvement of macroeconomic balances. In July
2017, the Moroccan monetary authorities canceled the implementation of the
floating exchange rate regime following a campaign of speculation against the
Moroccan dirham. On January 15, 2018, Morocco decided to switch from a fixed
exchange rate regime to a flexible regime, within fluctuation edges of +/- 2.5%
(instead of +/- 0.3%)
[3].
Under this new regime, the central bank will continue to intervene in the
foreign exchange market to ensure its liquidity. The need for this reform and
its timing can be explained by two reasons. The first is the predisposition of
the Moroccan economy to make this change of course since it reconciles all the
prerequisites (foreign exchange reserves, controlled deficit, currency in line
with its real value, etc.). The second reason is the turbulent environment in
which the global economy operates, which involves strong external risks. From
March 9, 2020, the Ministry of Economy, Finance and Administrative Reform, after
consulting the central bank, decided to widen the fluctuation band of the dirham
by +/- 2.5% to +/- 5% compared to a central rate set by BAM on the basis of a
basket of currencies composed of the euro (EUR) and the US dollar (USD) up to,
respectively, 60 % and 40%. This expansion comes after the objectives assigned
to the first phase have been achieved. The second phase has begun in a favorable
internal macroeconomic and financial context, marked in particular by an
appropriate level of foreign exchange reserves, controlled inflation (less than
1% in 2019), sustainable public debt and a solid financial sector with an
absence of any pressure on the MAD and stability
of its value. BAM continues, in accordance with its statute, to ensure the
proper functioning of the foreign exchange market and will intervene, if
necessary, on this market to ensure its liquidity. Among the expected objectives
of this widening of the MAD fluctuation band:
-
Give a strong signal to operators on the irreversibility of the reform of the
exchange rate regime.
-
Strengthen the role of the market in determining the exchange rate to deal with
exogenous shocks, easing pressures on foreign exchange reserves and preserving
export competitiveness.
-
Boost the foreign exchange market and encourage
economic operators to make greater use of hedging mechanisms.
-
Avoid a forced widening of the band in the event of
quotation of the MAD at the end of this band.
Since the 1980s, the increased openness of the
national economy to the outside has engaged us in a process of liberalisation,
hence the need to adapt a competitive exchange rate regime to reduce exchange
rate distortions and for greater adjustment.
In an increasingly turbulent environment,
Morocco needs a competitive and dynamic exchange rate in line with the
structuring projects undertaken and the major reforms initiated, with a view to
improving the competitiveness and productivity of the economic fabric. national.
Therefore, a more flexible exchange rate is undeniably important to the proper
functioning of the productive fabric.
Today, it is easier to demonstrate that the current exchange rate system is no
longer suited to the economic and social context, nor to the issues related to
Morocco's intention to be a global platform between Africa and the rest of the
world (Hefnaoui & Iaataren, 2022).
In addition, the Moroccan exchange system has
not experienced fundamental changes for more than 30 years, while over this same
period; the country has experienced a profound change in its economic and
financial architecture.
In this regard, it is time to lead a change in
the exchange system given the number of preconditions fulfilled. Indeed, the
choice of an optimal exchange rate regime is strictly linked to the
characteristics of the national economy in the light of the main orientations of
the monetary authorities as well as the economic stakes of the country.
Firstly, Morocco aims to support trade openness
with financial integration; for this the case of Morocco also has its
specificities and it would be necessary to identify them in order to clearly
define the target. If Morocco is open in commercial terms this is not the case
in financial terms.
In fact, openness is all the more fundamental
for economic development in that it offers Moroccan companies and operators a
number of opportunities to enhance their competitiveness, and this, due to the
fact that it bears real potential for attract investment, knowledge and know-how
from abroad. It is also a lever for improving the quality of services and the
performance of organizations, for improving the level of training provided and
for creating, in the long term, more jobs. In this sense, exchange rate
liberalization aims to improve competitiveness; it is important to check the
theorem of critical elasticities or else the condition of Marshall-Lerner
[4].
In order to stimulate competitiveness, the
liberalization of the exchange rate regime is an inevitable choice with the aim
of considerably improving the business environment as well as promoting the
emergence of young and successful companies and attracting productive foreign
companies. In addition, the choice of exchange rate flexibility aims to mitigate
external imbalances and exogenous shocks. Thus,
limiting the pressure on foreign exchange reserves is a very solid argument that
is sufficient in itself, without yet being explained, to justify the transition
to exchange rate flexibility. This transition would also allow the Moroccan
economy to acquire a macroeconomic instrument that acts as a shock
absorber (Khattab & Salmi, 2021).
Another argument in favor of flexibility lies in
the fact that the monetary authorities retain full freedom to act in terms of
monetary policy, mainly to conduct counter-cyclical monetary policies.
The tourism sector will also benefit more,
relying on the attractiveness of the Moroccan destination which will become more
accessible. Also for MREs
as long as the value of the dirham decreases,
which will indirectly benefit the economy.
However, the adoption of a floating exchange
rate would make it possible, on the one hand, to weaken the negative effects due
in particular to the lack of diversification of the Moroccan economy, and on the
other hand, to attach monetary policy more to the national economy and less to
an external anchor.
Indeed, Morocco has repeatedly expressed its
desire to pursue a policy of diversification in terms of products and partners.
The challenge is to find new partners outside the so-called classic ones such as
the European Union, with which the country has experienced several problems. In
addition, the global growth map is turning into the profit of some emerging
economies. However, less competitive companies will have to disappear to make
way for others who will be able to adapt to the new decimeters of the market.
Finally, this reform aims to create a
stimulating business environment that is a prerequisite for improving the
productivity and performance of the economy while reducing the dependence of
economic growth on climatic conditions. This reform is also a means of
strengthening Morocco's institutional capacities and improving its anticipatory
management style through the establishment of effective risk management. Thus,
the fragility of the fixed exchange rate regime in the face of the possibility
of a major external shock played a pivotal role in the liberalization of the
exchange rate regime.
Since the structural adjustment plan, the
Moroccan economy has entered an era of macroeconomic stabilization conducive to
the conduct of structural reforms and strategies for the future of the national
economy. As a result, Morocco has long maintained its historical and traditional
choice of anchoring to a basket composed of two main currencies: the Euro and
the Dollar. However, this choice will no longer serve the economic interests of
Morocco, which leads the monetary authorities to build a new model based on the
flexibility of the dirham exchange rate while exploring an optimal exchange rate
policy capable of improving competitiveness and absorb both internal and
external shocks in order to achieve the country's growth and development (Mezen
& Echkoundi, 2020).
No one can deny that the success of an exchange
rate regime remains dependent on the quality and relevance of macroeconomic
policies. On the other hand, the question that arises is: With the current
economic and structural conditions, could Morocco benefit from the advantages
that the transition to a more floating exchange rate regime could provide and
could it protect itself from the risks inherent in this transition?
The exchange rate has become an economic policy
mechanism in Morocco as in the rest of the world, which requires the
establishment of a set of accompanying procedures and structural reforms such as
the independence of monetary authorities and the accentuation of their decision
(modeling and forecasting inflation and its relationship with the international
situation).
The adoption of a floating exchange rate regime
also requires priority reforms of the financial and banking system, in addition,
the establishment of a rigorous legal and institutional framework to better meet
international standards.
Moving to a more flexible exchange rate regime
also requires improving market efficiency and liquidity. The central bank is
supposed to take the hand off gradually and improve transparency and the
transmission of information.
At the same time, the liberalization of the
capital account must be done in a gradual way to maintain the dynamic transition
towards a stable financial system. These reforms must be complemented by
rigorous control of capital flows in order to avoid unforeseen events.
On the other hand, fiscal policy should be
countercyclical. It should rely primarily on automatic stabilizers and respond
symmetrically to the business cycle (i.e., it should ease in bad times and
tighten in good times)
[5].
In short, there is
unanimity on the benefit that the transition to a more flexible regime will
generate and that it should take place when the conditions are favourable. In
the case of Morocco, the question is no longer to choose between a fixed or
flexible exchange rate regime but to specify the degree of management of the
exchange rate under a floating regime. In short, the Moroccan economy is not
ready to move to the total liberalization of the exchange rate of the dirham.
The Kingdom has therefore decided to wait until the effects of Covid-19 are
overcome.
In order to draw lessons from the transition to
a floating exchange rate regime and to identify the macroeconomic effects that a
country may suffer from its transition to such a regime, we are going to shed
light on a panel made up of several countries.
Case study of Chile (1980-2022)
In Chile, the flexible system was implemented
after good preparation of the ground and agreement between the decision to
change the regime and the elements that support it (implementation of a gradual
and implicit inflation targeting framework, provision of conduct of monetary
policy under a more flexible regime and preparation of market participants).
After the collapse of the Chilean fixed exchange
rate regime in the early 1980s, due to the country's high indebtedness, the
authorities decided to implement a "crawling peg" regime in 1982
essentially aimed at promoting a depreciation of the exchange rate to boost
exports, generate resources to refinance the external deficit and reduce
inflation. Between 1990 and 1997, the macroeconomic aggregates improved
markedly:
an increase in the annual growth rate
accompanied by an increase in exports, a fall in inflation and the unemployment
rate and a massive movement of capital inflows.
In 1998, the Asian crisis hit the country. The sources of financing have
deteriorated as well as the terms of exchange. The depreciation of the exchange
rate led to interventions by the authorities on the foreign exchange market
through a restrictive monetary policy and a contraction of the band (from 12.5%
to 2% at the top and 3.5% at the bottom).
Authorities spent several months defending the peso and then adopted a 7% band.
In 1999, the country moved to a flexible exchange rate regime.
On June 29, 2022, the exchange rate of the Chilean peso
against the US dollar reached a record high, flirting with 930 pesos per dollar,
after having exceeded the mark of 900 pesos per dollar on June 23.
The depreciation of the Chilean peso is explained by
several internal and external factors. Among the external factors, we obviously
include the impact of the reduction in monetary policies in the advanced
countries, in particular that of the Fed in the United States. Added to this is
also, in particular because of the slowdown in China's growth, the fall in the
price of copper, which reached very low levels at the end of June, falling below
the floor of 4 $ per pound on June 22 and reaching around 3.7 $ per pound on
June 30 (-15% over one month), i.e. its lowest price since February 2021.
Internal factors are also at work, such as the uncertainty linked to the new
Incorporation.
Among the results of this transition to floating:
Table 4: Results of the transition to floating - case
of Chile
Indicator |
Main results |
Change market |
-
Authorization of swap transactions
-
Gradual lifting of regulations |
Monetary Policy |
-
Reduction of inflation
-
Gradual abandonment of the exchange rate anchor for an inflation anchor. |
Capital account |
-
Gradual liberalization of capital outflows |
Banking sector |
-
Low level of dollarization |
Source: compiled by the author
Case study of Poland (1990-2022)
The country has gone through a gradual
flexibilization. The transition stages were in response to domestic and
international economic changes, as well as to the multiple objectives set by the
government: maintaining competitiveness, reducing inflation and integrating
domestic markets. During the 1980s, Poland experienced external and internal
imbalances. With a high debt ratio, weak growth and a large current account
deficit, the country thus adopted an adjustment plan which consisted of a
reallocation of resources between the public and private sectors and a
liberalization of prices leading to hyperinflation.
A deterioration of the economic situation in
Europe, and in particular in Germany, would have a much more harmful impact on
Polish growth. The country is by far Poland's largest trading partner,
accounting for 28.7% of its exports and 20.9% of its imports. A recession in
Germany could thus drag the Polish economy in its wake, given the strong
integration of the Polish economy in the German value chain.
The National Bank of Poland has been carrying
out a continuous tightening of monetary policy since October 2022, having raised
rates at each of its meetings since October. The key rate has now stood at 6%
since the beginning of June 2022. In addition, the outbreak of war in Ukraine
had led to a sudden depreciation of the zloty, which reached its historic low of
5 against the euro in early March before falling enjoy again.
Table 5: Results of the transition to floating – the
case of Poland
Indicator |
Main results |
Financial market |
-
Stability and strengthening of the financial system |
Monetary Policy |
-
Monetary policy stability |
Capital account |
-
Cautious capital account liberalization |
Banking sector |
-
The decisions taken were never revoked, otherwise they will influence
the credibility of the central bank imposing large costs on the economy. |
Source: compiled by the author
Case study of Brazil (1990-2022)
Brazil's transition to a flexible exchange rate
regime was motivated by the resorption of imbalances due to the inconsistency of
exchange rate policy, fiscal policy and monetary policy. In the early 1990s,
Brazil implemented a stabilization plan that led to:
-
The appreciation of the REER resulting in an appreciation of the local currency
and a decline in competitiveness;
-
The considerable drop in inflation;
-
The massive influx of capital.
The weak results of fiscal policy leading to
very high domestic interest rates have all led to the increase in consolidated
net public debt (42% of GDP in 1998) and to the deterioration of the
macroeconomic situation. Several external shocks hit the country's economy, such
as: the Mexican crisis in 1995, the Asian crisis in 1997 and the crisis in
Russia in 1998.
Faced with the constant rise in inflation (from
June 2020 to June 2022), the Central Bank has had to raise its key rate by 1175
bps since March 2021 to 13.75% at the end of 2022. According to the forecasts of
the Central Bank, maintaining the key rate at 13.75% until June 2023 is
envisaged at this stage. It should be noted, however, that the increase in
public expenditure planned for 2023, combined with uncertainties as to the
compensation measures necessary to avoid a greater imbalance in the public
accounts, favor the depreciation of the real against the USD, which could feed
imported inflation and postpone a possible monetary easing in the year.
Table 6: Results of the transition to floating - case
of Brazil
Indicator |
Main results |
Foreign exchange reserves |
-
Reduced to half due to speculative attacks and lack of trust. |
Monetary Policy |
-
The rapid implementation of a monetary and fiscal policy made it
possible to limit market instability |
Source: compiled by the author
Case study of Uruguay (1990-2022)
The transition from a "crawling band" to a
floating regime, in a context of a real financial crisis followed by a severe
depreciation of the peso and the insolvency of economic agents. The tape was
dropped without the necessary prerequisites. The country's experience shows how
the transition to floating in a context of absence of necessary elements and a
lack of perception of exchange risks can make the transition process difficult.
Uruguay implemented a
stabilization plan between 1990 and 2002, which made it possible in particular
to reduce hyperinflation; even after the abandonment of the stabilization plan
during the 2002 crisis, inflation did not exceed 10%.
The current account deficit should almost
completely shrink to -0.2% of GDP in 2022 (against -1.9% of GDP in 2021),
boosted by the dynamism of exports (soya, meat, dairy products) which benefit
from sustained prices. The external debt is on the rise and reaches nearly 86%
of GDP in 2021, of which around 15% of the total is to be repaid/refinanced
within 1 year, which should be easily achieved. The Uruguayan peso has also
tended to appreciate since the start of the year, boosted by sustained commodity
prices and inflows of foreign capital.
The Central Bank should continue its monetary
tightening in the face of rising inflationary pressures. In May 2022, inflation
thus reached 9.4% y/y, i.e. the highest level in 13 months.
Faced with rising inflation, the Central Bank
raised its key rate by 75 bps to 9.25% last May (+475 bps since the start of the
tightening in August 2021).
Table 7: Results of the transition to floating - case
of Uruguay
Indicator |
Main results |
Financial market |
-
Strong currency depreciation (more than 80%) |
Monetary Policy |
-
Soaring prices and rising inflation |
Banking sector |
-
Insolvent banks have closed (1/3 of the banking system) |
Source: compiled by the author
Case study of Ecuador (2009-2022)
A set of macroeconomic conditions and
operational aspects contributed to the failure of the move to greater
flexibility:
-
The underdeveloped and illiquid financial market;
-
Limited risk management capacity;
-
The absence of an appropriate intervention policy;
-
The limited degree of independence of monetary policy;
-
Adverse economic conditions and weak macroeconomic policy.
Ecuador's "dollarized" monetary regime has
limited macroeconomic policy options for responding to external shocks. As a
result, the country's budget deficit increased sharply and reached 5.1% of GDP
in 2009, mainly due to lower revenues from oil exports, increased energy
subsidies and public investments in strategic infrastructure projects; health,
education and social protection to bring about the long-needed improvements in
these areas and pave the way for sustainable growth.
Today, Ecuador is expected to post a current
account surplus for the 3rd successive year in 2022, boosted by the
trade balance surplus, supported by oil prices, as well as remittances from
expatriate workers who would remain dynamic. This, together with drawings from
the IMF credit line, is helping to strengthen the country's foreign currency
reserves. The conditions for access to market financing have also returned to
pre-pandemic levels, after peaking in Q1 2020 when the country was placed in
selective default by the rating agencies (following its request for deferral
payment to private creditors).
Table 8: Results of the transition to floating - case
of Ecuador
Indicator |
Main results |
Change market |
-
High pressure
-
Fall in foreign exchange reserves |
Monetary Policy |
-
Acceleration of inflation |
Banking sector |
-
Banking crisis due to lack of regulation and supervision of the sector. |
Source: compiled by the author
Case study of Egypt (1991-2022)
Egypt pegged its currency
to the dollar in 1991, but abandoned this policy in mid-2000. Pressures on the
pound have increased since 1998, when capital left the country after the Asian
crisis, while tourism suffered from terrorist attacks at home and abroad.
Furthermore, the appreciation of the dollar against the euro and the yen has
exacerbated the loss of competitiveness. Egypt initially responded to these
pressures by intervening in the foreign exchange market and tightening its
credit policy, but official reserves continued to decline and economic growth
slowed. Exchange rate pressures did not ease after an initial depreciation in
mid-2000, and in January 2001 the authorities adopted an adjustable fluctuation
band. However, pressures on the pound intensified again after the 11 September,
leading to a depreciation of more than 35% against the dollar from mid-2000 to
early 2003. official currency remained scarce at the prevailing official
exchange rate, and a parallel market emerged. After the recent move to a
floating regime, the currency depreciated by 20%, and the supply of currencies
in the official market increased.
After the Arab Spring of 2011, Egypt requested a
12 $ billion loan from the IMF in order to escape the economic crisis that hit
the country. Therefore, the implementation of a floating exchange rate regime in
November 2016 is part of the IMF's conditional rules for obtaining the loan.
Egypt has always experienced low and declining levels of foreign exchange
reserves, which is the result of several factors such as: political and regional
instability, weak investment climate, weakening competitiveness and concerns
about matters of security.
In 2022, the Central Bank of Egypt decided to
float the Egyptian pound to ensure “monetary and fiscal stability”. Egypt is
suffering from a shortage of dollars which is putting pressure on the Egyptian
pound and has severely slowed imports, on which the country of 104 million
people is heavily dependent. Experts estimate that the Egyptian pound has lost,
since the beginning of 2022, between 20% and 25% of its value against the
greenback. The local currency has been undergoing a slow depreciation since the
end of March and the decision of the Central Bank of Egypt to end the fixed
exchange rate system, which had led to a devaluation of more than 16% of the
Egyptian pound, in parallel with the 1% increase in interest rates.
Table 9: Results of the transition to floating - case
of Egypt
Indicator |
Main results |
Monetary Policy |
-
Rise in inflation and deterioration in consumer purchasing power |
Outdoor sector |
-
Reduction of external imbalance |
Tourism |
-
Increase in tourism receipts and FDI. |
Source: compiled by the author
Conclusion & Policy implications
Through this article, it is clear that Morocco
has gone through a long path of reforms in order to seek the stability of
macroeconomic fundamentals. It has thus opted for a gradual liberalization and a
more flexible exchange rate regime in order to gain more competitive advantage
compared to its competitors. This passage,
certainly studied and supported by the IMF and the Moroccan authorities are
optimistic as to the multiple advantages to be acquired such as the limitation
of the pressure on the foreign exchange reserves and the prevention of foreign
exchange crises, the strengthening of the resilience of the economy Morocco to
external shocks, supporting its competitiveness and improving its level of
growth. The reform should accompany the structural reforms experienced by the
national economy in recent years, particularly in terms of diversification,
openness and integration into the international economy. However, Morocco has a
“small economy” which, admittedly, has been opening up to the outside world for
four decades, but whose integration into international capital markets is in
progress. The transition to more flexibility
is not without risk, hence the imperative to set up an “optimal” exchange rate
regime. In this current international context marked by the Russo-Ukrainian
conflict, the move to a new stage in the process of making the exchange rate
regime more flexible, namely inflation targeting, must still wait; the ground
needs to be further prepared. The Kingdom is not yet ready for full
liberalization of the dirham, but it can further widen the fluctuation band.
The international sphere presents rich lessons
for the transition to floating (Egypt, Turkey, Brazil, etc.), tracing the
positive but also negative effects, to which Morocco must be vigilant by putting
in place the necessary measures to deal with these effects at the national level
in a good time. In short, questions relating to the flexibility of the exchange
rate regime are still numerous. The theoretical and managerial issues are also
of paramount importance, which gives rise to many future research works and
offers a favorable field for the development of scientific research.
References:
Ahmed, K., & Yahya, S. (2021). Contribution to the analysis of the Moroccan
dirham exchange rate volatility: Econometric modeling using the asymmetric
TGARCH model: Contribution à l’analyse de la volatilité du taux de change du
dirham marocain: Modélisation économétrique à l’aide du modèle asymétrique
TGARCH.
African Scientific Journal,
3(4), 460.
https://doi.org/10.5281/zenodo.5642815
Alhadj, M. S., Abessolo, Y. A., & Nemb, P. S. (2019).
Régime de change et
croissance économique: une investigation empirique à partir du rôle de la
qualité des institutions.
Global Journal Of Human-Social Science Economics, 19(1),7-18.
http://bit.ly/3G5wqnP
Bank Al Maghrib (2015). Report presented to
His Majesty the King.
Financial year
2015.P91.
http://bit.ly/3KmomkW
Bank Al Maghrib
(2017). Exchange rate reform. Press Workshops, February 13.
http://bit.ly/3TWjfLq
Camara, Y. (2014).
Exchange Rate Regimes and Economic Performance in Sub-Saharan Africa (pp.
194-196). HAL Archives ouverts.com, December 2014.
https://www.semanticscholar.org/author/Y.-S.-Camara/2094193097
De Mourat, R., Ocnarescu,
I., Renon, A. L., & Royer, M. (2015). Méthodologies de recherche et design: un
instantané des pratiques de recherche employées au sein d’un réseau de jeunes
chercheurs.
Sciences du design,
(1), 68-75.
https://doi.org/10.3917/sdd.001.0068
El Yamani, K., Charef, F., Qafas, A., & Jerry, M. (2018).
Evolution of
the management of the exchange rate regime in Morocco: what macroeconomic
effects?
International Journal of Business & Economic Strategy (IJBES), 8, 85-91.
http://ipco-co.com/IJBES/vol8/161.pdf
EL Yamani, K., Qafas, A., & Jerry, M. (2021).
Liens entre le taux de change et la croissance économique au Maroc : une
approche économétrique en équations simultanées.
International Journal of Accounting, Finance, Auditing, Management and
Economics, 2(6-1), 247-270.
https://doi.org/j4k3
Esaka, T., (2010). De facto exchange rate regimes
and currency crisis: are pegged regime with
capital
account liberalization really more prone to speculative attacks? Journal of
Banking & Finance,
34(6),
1109-1128.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2009.11.007
Esmak, H. (2016).
Prospects for an exchange rate regime in
Morocco: towards greater flexibility.
IOSR Journal of
Economics and Finance
(IOSR-JEF), 7(2), 120-136.
https://bit.ly/3JM7zpY
Hefnaoui, A., & Iaataren,
I. (2022). Débat théorique sur le choix du régime de change: Retour sur
l’opposition fixeflexible.
International Journal of Accounting, Finance,
Auditing, Management and Economics, 3(4-2), 202-214.
https://doi.org/10.5281/zenodo.6944353
Henri-Louis, V. (2019). Fixed exchange
rate/floating exchange rate, the case of Morocco. Policy Center, September,
PB-19/29, page 2.
http://bit.ly/3KlrIEQ
IMF Fiscal Monitor (2017). Achieving More with Less, April Edition.
IMF Fiscal Monitor (2021). Annual Report on Exchange Arrangements and
Exchange Restrictions.
https://doi.org/10.5089/9781513598956.012
Jouamaa, Y., & Rhiati, Z. (2021). L’impact du cours de change sur l’inflation :
cas du Maroc. Revue Internationale Des Sciences De Gestion, 4(1).
https://www.revue-isg.com/index.php/home/article/view/523
Mezen, M., & Echkoundi, M. (2020). Morocco's
adoption of the floating exchange rate: motivations, prerequisites and
transition strategy. Finance & International Finance, N°18 January.
https://doi.org/j4k4
Nakatani, R. (2018). Real and financial shocks, exchange rate regimes and the
probability of a currency crisis. Journal of Policy Modeling, 40(1),
60-73.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jpolmod.2017.10.004
Sabar, B., & Belhouari, I. (2018).
Determination of exchange rate misalignments: the case of Morocco.
Final project, INSEA, page 21.
Sylviane, G. J. (2019). Les enjeux de la réforme du régime de change du Maroc.
https://hal.science/hal-02287908
[1]This
bimetallism worked somehow, according to the inclinations of the power
which, sometimes, did not respect the content of the coins and
proceeded, in a search for signs of power, to unjustified coinage.
[2]Bank
of Morocco (2015). Report presented to His Majesty the King.
Financial year 2015.P91
[3]Bank Al Maghrib (2017).
Reform of the exchange rate regime, Press Workshops, 13 February.
[4]
The condition of Nawal-Marshall-Lerner also called theorem of critical
elasticities makes it possible to solve in an economic model taking into
account the trade balance of the
current balance
(exports less imports), the indeterminacy on
this one of a variation of the
rate exchange rate
(real or not). In other words, this condition
makes it possible to ensure that the sensitivity of trade to upheavals
in the exchange rate is greater than the reaction of inflation following
a similar variation in the exchange rate.
[5] IMF
Fiscal Monitor (2017), “Achieving
More with Less”,
April Edition.